The purpose of this article review is for you to learn to seek out information and to write an evaluative and critical review of a jo
The purpose of this article review is for you to learn to seek out information and to write an evaluative and critical review of a journal article. Your review must be submitted as a Word document. Use your name in the filename, along with the assignment name. For example: Smith,Fred.ArticleReview1.
Your written review will be approximately 3-4 double-spaced narrative pages, plus a title page (with Running head), page numbers, and in keeping with APA guidelines. An abstract is NOT required for the article review.
It is important for you to learn how to write about another author's work, which is different from regurgitating what the author wrote. Your review should not read as though you are the author of the article or material as opposed to reading form a critical perspective. The reader should clearly understand the difference between the author's contribution and your interpretation and evaluation of that contribution. Your review should show that you can recognize arguments and engage in critical thinking about the course content. Keep questions like these in mind as you read, make notes, and then write the review or critique. Critical thinking and application of course content is necessary for this assignment.
JOURNAL OF MANAGEMENT ACCOUNTING RESEARCH American Accounting Association Vol. 25 DOI: 10.2308/jmar-50492 2013 pp. 59–63
DISCUSSION OF
Knowing Versus Telling Private Information About a Rival Dhananjay (DJ) Nanda
University of Miami
ABSTRACT: Bagnoli and Watts (2013) show that a firm will always disclose its private
information when this information solely affects its rival’s product market decisions. This
result is robust to different competitive scenarios (Cournot or Bertrand competition),
features (product heterogeneity or private information quantity), and levels of commitment
(ex ante or ex post). I highlight how this result fits in the accounting disclosure literature,
describe the intuition behind the theory, and discuss its implications for future work.
Keywords: discretionary disclosure; product market competition; private information.
INTRODUCTION
O ver the last three decades, economics, finance, and accounting scholars have produced a large theoretical and empirical literature that examines firms’ discretionary disclosure policies. A central premise of the theory is ‘‘any entity making a disclosure will disclose information that
is favorable to the entity, and not disclose information unfavorable to the entity’’ (Dye 2001). Bagnoli and Watts (2013) add to this body of work by theoretically examining firms’ incentives to disclose information that solely pertains to its rivals’ product market prospects. They establish that a firm possessing such information will always disclose it, a result robust to several modeling assumptions.
In this discussion, I first provide a brief summary of the insights gained from the extant discretionary disclosure literature to highlight Bagnoli and Watts’ contribution. I then discuss their modeling assumptions to isolate the intuition behind their result. Finally, I conclude with remarks on the model’s implications and an area that perhaps provides a setting where one observes the modeled information environment.
DISCRETIONARY DISCLOSURE
Since the early 1980s, scholars have examined the incentives of informed agents revealing their
information to uninformed counterparties in an exchange economy (see Grossman 1981; Milgrom
1981).1 The most parsimonious representation of this exchange is described by a model of an asset seller
I thank Ramji Balakrishanan (editor) for helpful suggestions.
Published Online: April 2013
1 I will refrain from providing a survey of the entire discretionary disclosure literature as it is beyond the scope of this discussion. Verrecchia (2001) and Dye (2001) provide a comprehensive review of the theoretical accounting disclosure literature.
59
that possesses information about the asset’s value that potential buyers for that asset do not. Absent the
seller disclosing his/her private information, the buyers rationally suspect that the withheld information
adversely reflects on the asset’s value. Consequently, the price that sellers are willing to pay for the asset
incorporates a discount reflecting their conjecture regarding the amount by which the asset value is lower.
In equilibrium, the discount equals the amount that makes it in the seller’s best interest to disclose his/her
private information about the asset’s value. This tradeoff represents the ‘‘full disclosure’’ equilibrium and
is often referred to as the ‘‘unraveling’’ result.
What are the modeling assumptions that sustain the unraveling result? First, buyers know that
the seller has value-relevant information about the asset offered for sale. Second, buyers are
homogeneous in interpreting disclosure (and non-disclosure), i.e., they have identical beliefs about
the seller’s private information. Third, the seller’s disclosure is credible, i.e., it is truthful. Finally,
disclosure is costless to the seller and buyers alike. Subsequent work has attempted to overcome the
unraveling result of full disclosure in part to explain empirically observed partial disclosure;
economic agents do (sometimes) withhold information. Specifically, researchers have shown that
firms/managers do withhold information when the assumptions behind the ‘‘full disclosure’’ model
are violated. Broadly characterized, these modeling innovations are: (1) the seller may or may not
be informed (Dye 1985; Jung and Kwon 1988), (2) buyers have heterogeneous beliefs about the
seller’s information (Lintner 1969), (3) the seller’s disclosure may not be truthful (Milgrom and
Roberts 1986), and (4) the seller faces disclosure costs (Verrecchia 1983). In the presence of these
disclosure frictions, researchers have shown that the full disclosure equilibrium need not hold.
Bagnoli and Watts build on the disclosure-cost (innovation 4) narrative in the theoretical
accounting discretionary disclosure literature. Specifically, prior work has shown that firms facing
proprietary costs, i.e., costs only incurred if information is disclosed, will not always disclose
information as potential counterparties now interpret non-disclosure as avoiding costs rather than
suppressing unfavorable information. The simplest representation of proprietary costs is an
exogenous fixed cost only incurred if a firm chooses to disclose its private information (Verrecchia
1983). In this case the disclosure equilibrium is a threshold: only information that is sufficiently
favorable (above the threshold) is disclosed. Subsequent work endogenizes the proprietary cost of
disclosure by considering firm disclosure policy in an imperfectly competitive product market
where the cost of disclosing private information arises from competitors gaining a strategic
advantage in their pricing or output choices (Darrough and Stoughton 1990). In this literature, the
disclosure equilibrium is affected by modeling choices: cost- or demand-related information,
Cournot or Bertrand competition, and whether the firm chooses its disclosure policy before or after
observing the information (see Darrough 1993).
KNOWING VERSUS TELLING
Bagnoli and Watts study a firm’s disclosure policy in a product-market setting, with two
competing firms facing a linear demand curve and constant marginal production costs over a single
period. Both firms are solely concerned with maximizing firm profits at the end of the period.
Consequently, valuation, agency, and dynamic issues are absent. A firm privately observes
information that solely pertains to its rival’s operations (demand or cost related) and truthfully
discloses it, if at all, pre-production. The information stochastically observed by a firm is fully
revealing of either the demand or the cost parameters of its rival. The information structure modeled
in Bagnoli and Watts is its novel contribution to the accounting disclosure literature. Specifically,
the assumption that a firm’s private information is decision-irrelevant to itself but is relevant to its
rival’s decisions leads to a robust full disclosure equilibrium, enhancing our understanding of the
role played by proprietary costs in affecting firm disclosure policy.
60 Nanda
Journal of Management Accounting Research Volume 25, 2013
Why is it in the best interests of the firm to always disclose its private information about its
rival’s economic prospects? To describe the intuition behind the result, I begin with the ex ante disclosure commitment scenario where a firm chooses its policy before observing the information
so it does not know if the information is favorable or unfavorable to its own economic prospects. If
the firm chooses not to disclose, its rival is uninformed and acts based solely on the expected value
of the demand or cost parameters, which leads to either choosing to produce too much (or price too
low) or too little (price too high). Given the assumptions of linear demand and cost, the expected
profit of the informed firm is convex and increasing in the information’s favorability (to itself ).
Consequently, a firm always prefers disclosing its private information (a gamble) to withholding the
information and having its rival choose prices or quantities based on the expected values of the
parameters. Thus, the unraveling result of full disclosure occurs when a firm’s private information
does not have any direct effect on the informed firm’s demand or cost functions.2
If a firm chooses its disclosure policy after observing the information and knowing whether it is
favorable or unfavorable (ex post disclosure), a similar full disclosure equilibrium results—the
reason being that non-disclosure by the informed firm is rationally perceived by the rival as
information that is unfavorable to the informed firm. Consequently, the rival will increase price or
quantity, thereby reducing the informed firm’s expected profit. Consequently, absent any
exogenous disclosure costs, the informed firm always discloses its information. In both cases, ex ante and ex post disclosure, private information (solely) about a rival (solely) has proprietary benefits.
IMPLICATIONS AND EXTENSIONS
Bagnoli and Watts assume that the firm’s private information is solely decision-relevant to its
rival. This naturally leads to the inquiry: What information can a firm possess about a rival that is
decision-irrelevant for itself? The authors provide several examples in the manuscript of firms
disclosing information that potentially affects their rival’s product markets. For instance, Bagnoli
and Watts cite the example of AT&T’s disclosure of the effect of smartphones on wireless
networks, which is decision-relevant to Verizon which is introducing a new device that would use
such networks. However, it seems that this information is decision-relevant for AT&T as well
because the company also supports smartphones on its data networks. The other examples in the
paper also suggest that the publicly disclosed information is decision-relevant for both the
disclosing firm and its rival. So, why is it so difficult to cite examples that fit the modeled
information environment?
There are a few potential explanations for the difficulty in citing examples of firms disclosing
information that does not affect their own business. First, there are potential costs associated with
acquiring information about a rival and disclosing it publicly, which are unmodeled in Bagnoli and
Watts. For instance, industrial espionage is prohibited in the U.S. under the Economic Espionage
Act of 1996 (18 U.S.C. §§). Because acquiring and disclosing such information has costs, the
no-disclosure equilibrium likely prevails with regard to such information. Second, perhaps firms
that possess information about their rival choose to disclose it surreptitiously. For instance, blogs
and chat rooms provide some anonymity to a person disclosing information and are yet effective in
disseminating such information. Another likely reason is that the single-period model is perhaps too
restrictive in explaining empirically observed behaviors.
A single-period setting, as modeled in Bagnoli and Watts, is analytically appealing because of
its parsimony and ability to provide ‘‘clean’’ comparative static predictions. However, firm
2 If the information affects the informed firm’s demand parameter (m ¼ 1 case under Bertrand competition in Bagnoli and Watts), then it prefers to suppress disclosure.
Discussion of Knowing Versus Telling Private Information About a Rival 61
Journal of Management Accounting Research Volume 25, 2013
disclosure policy is based on strategic considerations that are multi-period in nature. For instance, a
firm may suppress information that is potentially favorable to its rivals to discourage potential
entrants into its product market. Similarly, unfavorable information disclosures may create entry
barriers or potential exits by rivals. Consequently, multi-period considerations potentially lead to
other equilibriums than the full-disclosure equilibrium established in Bagnoli and Watts.
Multi-period models also provide the opportunity to explore other firm considerations that affect
disclosure policy such as agency issues. For instance, disclosing favorable information about a rival
may benefit the disclosing firm but may be personally costly to its manager if it adversely affects
his/her short-term performance appraisal. Overall, the Bagnoli and Watts framework provides a
starting point for future research to examine dynamic or multi-period considerations in firm
disclosures of information about rivals.
The labor market provides a potential setting where a party (firm or agent) often is privy to
information about its rival and this information is decision-irrelevant for itself. For instance, firms
possess information about an employee’s ability that is decision-relevant for a competitor
attempting to hire away the employee. Potential recruiters solicit recommendations from past
employers in an effort to gather this information. In academia, promotion and tenure decisions are
affected by evaluations of a candidate’s scholarship by employees of a rival institution. Disclosing
information in this setting is inherently strategic, with few proprietary costs, yet we often observe
credible full disclosure of private information. In fact, the private information in labor markets has
the Bagnoli and Watts feature of proprietary benefits that accrue to the disclosing entity. Even
though the labor market is not modeled in this paper, the insight that an entity with information
about its rival always discloses is applicable.
CONCLUSION
Bagnoli and Watts (2013) demonstrate that firms always disclose their private information
about their rival’s product market prospects, if this information does not pertain to their own
demand or cost characteristics and if disclosure is costless. Consequently, information about a rival
has proprietary benefits to a disclosing firm. The full-disclosure equilibrium derived in this paper is
robust to several modeling choices and assumptions. As such, this paper complements the existing
disclosure literature that has until now focused on proprietary costs of disclosure.
The Bagnoli and Watts paper sets the stage for further research on disclosure of information
that is not necessarily decision-relevant to the disclosing party. In my discussion, I identify two
potential areas of inquiry that may prove fruitful. First, to explore the strategic nature of disclosures,
multi-period models are required where dynamic incentive issues and firm entry-exit decisions can
be explored. Second, since we observe the Bagnoli and Watts modeled information structure in
labor markets, future extensions of this model should consider exploring disclosure behavior in
these settings.
REFERENCES
Bagnoli, M., and S. G. Watts. 2013. Knowing versus telling private information about a rival. Journal of
Management Accounting Research 25 (1).
Darrough, M. N. 1993. Disclosure policy and competition: Cournot vs. Bertrand. The Accounting Review
68: 534–561.
Darrough, M. N., and N.M. Stoughton. 1990. Financial disclosure policy in an entry game. Journal of
Accounting and Economics 12: 480–511.
Dye, R. A. 1985. Disclosure of nonproprietary information. Journal of Accounting Research 23: 123–145.
62 Nanda
Journal of Management Accounting Research Volume 25, 2013
Dye, R. A. 2001. An evaluation of ‘‘essays on disclosure’’ and the disclosing literature in accounting.
Journal of Accounting and Economics 32: 181–235.
Grossman, S. J. 1981. The role of warranties and private disclosure about product quality. Journal of Law and Economics 24: 461–483.
Jung, W. O., and Y. K. Kwon. 1988. Disclosure when the market is unsure of information endowment of
managers. Journal of Accounting Research 26: 146–153.
Lintner, J. 1969. The aggregation of investors’ diverse judgments and preferences in purely competitive
security markets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 4: 347–400.
Milgrom, P. 1981. Good news and bad news: Representation theorems and applications. Bell Journal of Economics 12: 380–391.
Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts. 1986. Relying on the information of interested parties. Rand Journal of Economics 17: 18–32.
Verrecchia, R. E. 1983. Discretionary disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics 5: 365–380.
Verrecchia, R. E. 2001. Essays on disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics 32: 97–180.
Discussion of Knowing Versus Telling Private Information About a Rival 63
Journal of Management Accounting Research Volume 25, 2013
Copyright of Journal of Management Accounting Research is the property of American Accounting Association and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.
Collepals.com Plagiarism Free Papers
Are you looking for custom essay writing service or even dissertation writing services? Just request for our write my paper service, and we'll match you with the best essay writer in your subject! With an exceptional team of professional academic experts in a wide range of subjects, we can guarantee you an unrivaled quality of custom-written papers.
Get ZERO PLAGIARISM, HUMAN WRITTEN ESSAYS
Why Hire Collepals.com writers to do your paper?
Quality- We are experienced and have access to ample research materials.
We write plagiarism Free Content
Confidential- We never share or sell your personal information to third parties.
Support-Chat with us today! We are always waiting to answer all your questions.
